Changing pattern of Agrarian structure in India: A Preliminary Note
[Citation: Gaurang R. Sahay, Changing pattern of Agrarian structure in India: A Preliminary Note (2009, Unpublished)]
The term agrarian structure denotes a framework of social relationships in which all agricultural activities such as production, marketing and consumption are carried out. The institution or the framework of social relationships determines how and by whom land is cultivated, what kind of crops can be produced and for what purpose, how food and agricultural incomes can be distributed, and in what way or in what terms the agrarian sector is linked to the rest of economy or society.
Agrarian structure or its various dimensions and
dynamics such as land reforms, Green Revolution and agriculture
labour have been the major concerns of Indian social scientists,
particularly sociologists and social anthropologists. They have tried
to understand and analyse them in different forms by using different
concepts right from the time of independence. To present a systematic
and detailed picture of the Indian agrarian structure and its various
dynamics it has been proposed to divide the trajectory of the problem
into three phases: pre-colonial phase, colonial phase, and
post-colonial phase.
1.
Agrarian Structure during the Pre-colonial Period
The
discourses on the pre-colonial Indian
agrarian structure are quite homogenous in terms of the ideas and
lessons that they provide. The main concepts which were developed and
used to understand the pre-colonial Indian
agrarian structure are: 1. Oriental Despotism (Montesquieu, Hegel,
Bernier and James Mills), 2. Asiatic Mode of Production (Karl Marx)
and 3. Prebendal Patrimonialism (Max Weber). The concepts are, more
or less similar, similar to each other in terms of their contents and
meanings. They bring out following features of the
pre-colonial Indian agrarian structure:
- Absence of private property in land
- Possession and use of land on communal basis
- State or king as the absolute owner of land
- Torrid climatic environment
- State controlled irrigation or public hydraulic works
- Division of agrarian society into self-sufficient, autonomous and isolated village communities or village as idyllic little republics
- All kinds of relationships organized around the institution of caste or, to put in different words, caste system as the basis of self-sustaining and self-producing Indian village communities
- Surplus labour as tribute to the despotic king
- Absence of classes leading to servile social equality
- Absence of hereditary nobility
- General slavery or exploitation of the people directly by the despotic state or king without any relationship of dependence and exchange at the lower levels and juridical restraints
These structural features made Indian society, which was
overwhelmingly agrarian, ever static and historyless. Marx writes,
‘Indian society has no history at all, at least no known history.
What we call its history is but the history of the successive
invaders who founded empires on the passive basis of that unresisting
and unchanging society’ (Marx 1968: 185).
Colonial ethnographers and British
administrators-cum-sociologists such as Baden Powell, Henry Maine and
Charles Metcalfe followed both in words and spirits such an
‘orientalist’ understanding of Indian social formation and its
agrarian structure. To quote Metcalfe, ‘The village communities are
little republics, having nearly everything they want within
themselves, and almost independent of foreign relations. They seem to
last where nothing else lasts. Dynasty after dynasty tumbles down;
revolution succeeds revolution; Hindu, Pathan, Mughal, Maharatta,
Sikh, English are masters in turn; but the village communities remain
the same’ (quoted from Cohn 1987: 213).
However, historical research by Indian scholars,
particularly in post-independent India, has convincingly contested
this orientalist understanding of Indian socio-economic structure,
and proved that
- Everyone had no equal rights over land or land produce. The village did not hold its land in common. Common were its officials and servants (Neale 1962: 21).
- The land rights could even be purchased and sold. The agrarian society was internally differentiated in terms of class, and was unstable and not self-sufficient (Habib 1963:154).
- There was a sizeable population who worked as labourer (Dharma Kumar 1992).
- The authorities discriminated between the different sections of landowners while fixing the revenue demands. The large landowners were required to pay less (Dharma Kumar 1992).
- Pre-colonial agrarian relations were also not free of conflicts and tensions (Habib 1963; Moore 1966; Dhanagare 1983).
f) Production of crops, particularly cash crops, for
market (Habib 1982).
2.
Agrarian Structure during the Colonial Rule
The
British colonial rule did many things and introduced many measures to
reorganize rural/agrarian society in a framework that make governance
easy, profitable and manageable. Most important noteworthy measures
with far reaching consequences are following:
a) The Land Tenure/Revenue System
1)
The Permanent Settlement System
Under
this measure, the intermediary Zamindars (the tax collecting
officials in earlier regime) was granted ownership right over land
from which they previously only had the rights to collect revenues.
2)
The Ryotwari System
Under
this, the actual land tillers were given formal property rights over
land. The Royat was a tenant of the state, responsible for paying
revenue directly to the state treasury, and could not be evicted as
long as he paid his revenue.
3)
The Mahalwari or Malgujari System
Under
this system, the village was identified as unit of assessment. Though
an individual cultivator in a village was made owner of the land, the
villagers were asked to pay the revenue collectively. A member of the
dominant family of the village was generally given the responsibility
of collecting the revenue.
These colonial measures introduced ‘more intensive and
systematic exploitation’ (Guha 1983: 7) and forced the peasants to
become increasingly involved with the market, even when they did not
have the capacity to produce surplus. These measures brought about
major changes in the agrarian structure. The most significant ones
are following:
b)
Commercialization of Agriculture
It
means a shift in the agrarian economy from production for consumption
(food crops) to production for market (cash crops). The demand of raw
material in British industries and the manifold increase in the land
revenue compelled the peasantry to shift to cash crops (Blyn 1966).
One obvious consequence of this shift in cropping patterns was a
significant increase in the vulnerability of local population to
famines (Kumar 1982; Sen 1976).
c)
Commodification of Land
Due
to colonial policies land began to acquire the features of a
commodity. The moneylender, who until then lent keeping a peasant’s
crops in mind, began to see his land as a mortgageable asset against
which he could lend money.
d)
De-industrialization of the Indian economy
The
influx of cheap goods from England after the industrial revolution
hastened the process of de-industrialization by ruining the village
artisans that also resulted into the massive pressure on cultivatable
land.
e)
Land Alienation
It
was a pan-Indian phenomenon irrespective of the system of revenue
settlement: Zamindary, Ryotwari, or Mahalwari (Dhanagare 1983). In
the past the professional moneylenders generally did not evict the
peasant from his land but made him tenant if he did not pay back the
debt, whereas the landlords evicted him from the land and made him
landless. Thus tenancy and landlessness grew significantly
(Bhattacharya 1985; Bailey 1958).
f)
Conservation and/or Dissolution of the elements of Pre-colonial
Agrarian Structure
There
is almost a consensus among scholars that while colonial rule
destroyed some pre-colonial elements of agrarian structures, it also
preserved many. It broke down earlier structures without
reconstituting them, and, as Utsa Patnaik argues, the ‘bourgeois
property relations’ developed without corresponding development of
capitalist relations of production and forces of production in
agriculture (Patnaik 1990; Banaji 1990). Alavi argues that colonial
rule brought about peripheral capitalism in India which generated a
disarticulated form of ‘generalised commodity production’ because
the surplus agriculture produce was reinvested not in the local
economy but in the metropolitan centers (Alavi 1990: 170).
3.
Agrarian Structure in Post-colonial India
Independence
from the colonial rule marked the beginning of a new phase in the
history of agrarian structure. The main objective of the Indian state
was to transform the stagnant and backward economy and to make sure
that the benefits of transformation and growth were not monopolized
by a particular section of the society. Keeping this in background
the govt. of India introduced various measures. Significant ones are
following:
a)
Land Reforms
Land
reforms in independent India finds its raison d ĂȘtre in the
constitution which begins with the Preamble that is based on the four
cornerstones of justice, liberty, equality and fraternity, and
further strengthened by certain specific provisions, particularly the
directive principles of state policy, which set out that the state
shall, in particular, direct its policies such that:
- The citizens, men and women equally, have the right to an adequate means of livelihood;
- The ownership and control of the resources of the community are so distributed as to subserve the common good;
- The operation of the economic system does not result in the concentration of wealth and other means of production to the common detriment.
Land reforms measures were among the most significant
efforts of the state to achieve these goals. The govt. of India
directed its states to abolish intermediary tenures, regulate rent
and tenancy rights, confer ownership rights on tenants, impose
ceilings on holdings, distribute the surplus land among the rural
poor, and facilitate consolidation of holdings. A large number of
legislations were passed by the state governments over a short period
of time.
The actual implementation of these legislations and
their impact on the agrarian structure is, however, an entirely
different story. Most of these legislations had loopholes that
allowed the landlords to tamper with the land records, evicting their
tenants, and using other means to escape the legislations (Joshi
1976; Radhakrishnan 1989).
Despite over all failure, land reforms succeeded in
weakening the hold of absentee landlords over rural society and
assisted in the emergence of a class of substantial peasants and
petty landlords as the dominant political and economic group (Bell
1974: 196; Chakravarti 1975: 97-8; Byres 1974). However, it was only
in rare cases that the landless, most of whom belonged to class of
dalits, received land. The beneficiaries, by and large, belonged to
middle level caste groups who traditionally cultivated land as a part
of the calling of their castes. Otherwise, the land holding structure
continued to be fairly iniquitous.
b)
Provisions for institutional Credit
The
govt. of India introduced various provisions of Institutional credit
to weaken the hold of traditional moneylenders over the peasantry.
According to the RBI Report 1969, approximately 91per cent of the
credit needs of the cultivators were being met by informal sources of
credit. 69.7 per cent of it came from usurious moneylenders. The
govt. asked cooperative credit societies and commercial banks to lend
to the agricultural sector on priority basis. However, the studies
showed that much of their credit went to the relatively better off
sections of agrarian society and the poor continued to depend on the
servile exploitative sources (Thorner 1964; Oommen 1984; Jodhaka
1995).
c)
The Community Development Programme (CDP)
This
programme, which was patterned on American experiences, was launched
on 2 October 1952, and its objective was to provide the substantial
increase in agricultural production and improvement in basic
services, which would ultimately lead to overall development of the
all sections of agrarian society. However, it failed in its objective
and resulted in helping only those who were already powerful in the
village.
d)
The Green Revolution
Green
Revolution is an agricultural development project that includes
higher yielding variety seeds (HYV) and other fertility enhancing
inputs i.e. chemical fertilizer, controlled irrigation facilities and
pesticides. The components of the project consisted of providing
cheap institutional price incentives, marketing and research
facilities.
The idea of Green Revolution was based on the ‘trickle
down’ theory of economic growth. It carried the conviction that
agriculture could be peacefully transformed through the quite working
of science and technology without the social costs of mass upheaval
and disorder (Frankel 1971: Chat. V).
The Green Revolution led to a substantial increase (at
the rate of 3 to 5 per cent per annum) in the agricultural production
(Byres1972). However, it did not mean same thing to all sections of
the agrarian society. While bigger farmers had enough surplus of
their own to invest in the new capital-intensive farming, for smaller
farmers it meant additional dependence on borrowing, generally from
informal sectors (Jodhaka 1995: A124; Harriss 1987: 231). The Green
Revolution also resulted into a totally new kind of mobilization of
surplus producing farmers who demanded a better deal for the
agricultural sector (Dhanagare 1991; Brass 1994; Gupta 1997).
Did the benefits of Green
Revolution ‘trickle down’ to agricultural labourers? It has been
one of the most debated questions in the studies on agrarian change
in independent India. It is an almost accepted fact among the
scholars that the Green Revolution has made the countryside
prosperous in general terms, however, it has also increased economic
inequalities in the villages (Bardhan 1970). The wages of
agricultural labour has gone up but, due to increase in the prices,
their purchasing power has gone down (Bagchi1982; Dhanagare 1988).
The proportion of agriculture labour to total population increased
mainly due to depeasantisation (Aggarwal 1971). The Green Revolution
also helped in making the agricultural labour free from relations of
patronage and institutionalized dependency (Bremman 1974; Beteille
1971; Gaugh 1981; Bhalla 1976). It increased the ‘proletarianisation’
of labour (Brass 1990). Over all, it has been assessed that due to
the Green Revolution a smaller class of big peasants established
dominance over the larger class of agriculture labour.
The changes brought about by the
Green revolution and other measures of the govt. of India in the
agrarian structure generated a debate among the Marxist scholars on
the nature of mode of production in Indian agriculture. The debate
was started by Rudra’s (1970) claim that agrarian India is still
feudal. Most of the participants in the debate, such as
Chattopadhyay (1972a, 1972b), Gough (1980), Banaji (1972, 1973,
1977), Harriss (1982) and Breman (1985) argue that capitalist mode of
production indeed is on its way to dominating the agrarian economy of
India and most certainly that of the regions which has experienced
the Green Revolution. Some others, like Bhaduri (1973a, 1973b),
Pradhan Prasad (1973, 1974), N. K. Chandra (1974) and Ranjit Sau
(1973, 1975, 1976) hold a different view about the nature of agrarian
society. They opine that agrarian mode of production in India
exhibits some features of capitalism; however, its basic nature is
semi-feudal.
Basic
Readings
Bardhan,
P. 1970. Land, Labour and Rural Poverty: Essays in Development
Economics. Delhi: Oxford University
Press.
Beteille,
A. 1974. Studies in Agrarian Social Structure. Delhi: Oxford
University Press.
Frankel,
F. R. 1971. India’s Green Revolution: Economic Gains and
Political Costs. Bombay: Oxford
University Press.
Joshi,
P. C. 1976. Land Reforms in India: Trends and Perspectives. New
Delhi: Allied Publishers.
Lehman,
D. (ed.). 1974. Agrarian Reform and Agrarian Reformism: Studies
of Peru, Chile, China, and India.
London: Faber and Faber.
O’Leary,
B. 1989. The Asiatic Mode of Production: Oriental Despotism,
Historical Materialism and Indian
History. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Patnaik,
U. (ed.). 1990. Agrarian Relations and Accumulation: The ‘Mode of
Production Debate in India’. Delhi:
Oxford University Press.
Raychaudhury,T.
and Irfan Habib (ed.). The Cambridge Economic History
of India, vol.1. Delhi: Orient Longman.
Shanin,
T. (ed.), 1987. Peasants and Peasant Societies. London: Blackwell.
This article is wonderful... helped as lot to understand the facts crisply .. Sir please keep posting the Sociology topics.Thanks !!
ReplyDeleteawesome
ReplyDeleteThanks for this updated list. Waiting for more sites…
ReplyDeleteAluminium Scaffolding Rental In Delhi NCR